top of page

Why the Quantity Theory of Money is Wrong


The Quantity Theory of Money is the idea that the primary determinant of movements in the price level is demand-pull inflation stemming from increases in the money supply. It is represented by the equation MV = PY, where M is the money supply, V is the velocity of money, P is the price level, and Y is the total amount of goods and services for sale. The theory states that as the money supply increases, V and Y tend to stay constant and P increases proportionately with M. Monetarists and neoclassical economists use this equation to argue that increases in the money supply will always lead to proportionate increases in consumer prices, but this is wrong for several reasons.


First, QTM tells you nothing about whether the new money is being spent.

People cannot bid up prices unless they actually try to make purchases on goods that have elastic prices. Merely considering the quantity of money tells you nothing about whether everyone has money or if only one person has most of the money. This distributional analysis is important because the marginal propensity to spend money on consumer goods decreases as wealth increases. If new money goes to businesses or to people whose material needs are already met, the amount of spending on consumer goods will not increase as much as if that same money went to someone who needed to make an immediate purchase to satisfy their material needs. Even if the new money is given to poor people, the recipient may have a reason or incentive to save some of that money.


Second, even if money is spent, merely looking at the quantity of money tells you nothing about what that money is being spent on.

Even if the new money is being spent, we do not know what people will spend it on. Recipients of new money who do not save it they may want to spend it on something which functionally has an unlimited supply, such as online media, or they may want to invest it in financial assets or gamble it away. They may send it to relatives living in other countries. None of this would have any direct impact on consumer prices. Furthermore, if the new money was spent on productive investment, this would create resistance to price increases, which would have the opposite effect that the QTM predicts.


Third, the Y in MV=PY is not fixed unless an economy is at full employment.

Even if we know that the recipients of new money are spending it on consumer goods, most of the time, firms have flexibility in their output decisions, and the empirical research shows that they do adjust output and employment according to expected demand for their products. (McIntosh 1989) If firms increase output and employment according to expected demand, we should not expect increased demand to lead directly to increased prices.

However, even when an economy (or a specific industry) is at full employment, firms do not behave in the way this equation suggests. First, 55% of firms change prices no more than once per year, and 75% of firms change prices no more than twice per year, meaning that most firms are not responding to monthly or even quarterly updates regarding the aggregate money supply. (Blinder 1991) According to Blinder's price study, the most important factors in firms pricing decisions are (1) whether they can lengthen delivery times or provide fewer auxiliary services, (2) the desire to avoid being the first in their industry to raise prices, (3) increases in labor or material costs, and (4) implicit understandings with their customers to not raise prices when markets are tight. Additionally, according to Blinder, increases in costs gave rise to price changes more quickly than increases in demand. Because increases in demand cause a slow response to prices, there is time for other effects to dampen or interfere with the demand cost channel. Consequently, if (1) firms only raise prices once per year, (2) in response to increased demand, firms can adjust auxiliary services, lengthen delivery times, and are incentivized to maintain low prices to preserve market share, and (3) firms more readily raise prices in response to cost increases than demand increases, it is always more likely that a price hike in a competitive market is more likely a response to increased input costs than a response to increased consumer demand.

The way the quantity of money is supposed to work is that firms allegedly will check inflation expectations and statements by the Federal Reserve (which are derived from predictions about the quantity of money) and adjust their prices to keep up. However, there’s simply no empirical evidence that this takes place. Truman Bewley's presentation to the Boston Federal Reserve Bank in 2016 provides us with insight into the emptiness of this hypothesis. He found that long term contracts and integration of production processes make rapid price changes very difficult and adversarial. “Literally no one in the study "mentioned expectations about inflation or future Federal Reserve policy as a factor, and questions along these lines provoked ridicule (emphasis added). Bewley hypothesized that inflation expectations might affect prices by impacting futures prices, which affect long-term fixed prices. However, Fed chairman Ben Bernake, speaking in 2008, conceded that the futures markets are highly unreliable predictors of commodity price increases, so it is unclear through what channel inflation expectations ultimately lead to price increases.

Monetarists respond by stating that “the reason firms don’t check or respond to inflation expectations is that expectations are well anchored, but if there were a major shock to the real economy, then expectations would become unanchored, and firms would respond to new information and raise prices to keep up with expectations.” However, this makes the theory unfalsifiable and unscientific. Virtually everyone concedes that a major shock to the real economy would have inflationary effects regardless of whether firms agreed on inflation expectations. If there were a drought, food prices would go up because food would be scarce. The fact that firms would expect food prices to go up is superfluous decoration distracting from events in the real economy.


Fourth, another channel through which increases to the money supply is supposed to lead to inflation is downward pressure on the exchange rate, but this effect is much weaker than most people realize.

The exaggerated concern for this risk is based on a misunderstanding of the volume and flow of international trade. Exchange rate depreciation only has the potential to directly affect the price of imported items; in an average country the aggregate value of imports is less than 30% of the country's GDP, and in the U.S., only about 10% of personal consumption expenditures are on imported goods or goods containing imports. Even then, the relationship between currency depreciation and inflation is not one-for-one because exporters sometimes relinquish profit margins to maintain market share or because they must compete with the price of equivalent domestic-produced goods. In 1989, the Federal Reserve of St. Louis’s research officer, R. W. Hafer, performed a thorough review of the literature and concluded that the view “that a falling foreign exchange value of the dollar means higher U.S. inflation” was “off the mark.” Most of the studies he reviewed found that a 10% dollar depreciation only led to around a 1% increase in inflation, but the studies he reviewed that attempted to separate dollar depreciation from oil price shocks found that a 10% dollar depreciation led to an increase in inflation of 0.02% or had “no appreciable effect.”


Fifth, a broader examination of the empirical data does not show that increasing the money supply directly and immediately causes inflation.


For detailed empirical analysis, read this paper written by The Private Debt Project and review the accompanying underlying data. In short, significant price increases are just as likely to occur without any expansion of the money supply as they are likely to occur following a major expansion for the money supply over short periods. Over longer periods the quantity of money and the consumer price level are correlated, but that causation is bidirectional but likely goes primarily in the opposite direction. Rather than firms unilaterally raising prices - and sacrificing market share - because the government announced lower rates or a new spending program, consumers increase their borrowing to meet their material needs when prices go up. To illustrate with a real-life example, when someone wants a new car, they research the model they want and then find a way to pay for it, which may include borrowing money up to the previously-agreed-upon price. If the price of the car goes up, then they borrow more. They do not do the opposite. They do not go to their bank, ask “What’s the most you’d be willing to lend me?,” then go to the car dealership and say “The bank loaned me this much money; sell me the most expensive car I can get with this money.” There is some increased willingness to pay for consumer goods that results from easier lending conditions, but generally people seek to avoid debt and make decisions about what consumer goods they can afford before considering interest rates.


bottom of page